7.71 In each country, financial markets regulation has been affected by the structure and the evolution of the domestic financial system as well as by the legal system in place. The different objectives of regulation, the different markets, and intermediaries have been assigned to one or more authorities.
7.72 Financial regulation aims to correct market imperfections and unfair distribution of the resources, while pursuing four general objectives: macro-stability of the (p. 187) system, micro-stability of the intermediaries, market transparency and investor protection, and, last but not least, efficiency.22
7.73 The first objective of financial market regulation is the pursuit of macro-stability.23 Safeguarding the stability of the system translates into macro-controls over currencies, interest rates, financial instruments in aggregate, exchanges, payment and, possibly, settlement systems which are among the typical functions of central banks; it also means the function of lender of last resort.
7.74 The second objective pertains to the micro-stability (prudential supervision) of the intermediaries and it can be subdivided into two categories: general rules on the stability of all business enterprises and entrepreneurial activities, such as the legally required amount of capital, borrowing limits, integrity requirements, entry/exit controls; and more specific rules due to the special nature of financial intermediation, such as risk-based capital ratios, limits to portfolio investments and the regulation of off-balance activities, the managing of deposit insurance funds or investor compensation schemes. Furthermore, micro-stability controls can focus on the entities managing financial exchanges, clearing houses, and securities settlement systems.
7.75 The third objective of financial regulation is transparency—in the market and of intermediaries—ie investor protection. This is linked to the more general objective of equity in the distribution of the available resources and may be viewed as the search for ‘equity in the distribution of information as a precious good’ among operators.
7.76 At the market level, transparency rules impose equal and homogeneous treatment (eg rules regarding takeovers, public offers, and conflict of interest) and the correct dissemination of information (insider trading, manipulation and, more generally, the rules dealing with exchanges, micro-structure, and price-discovery mechanisms). At the intermediary level, such rules aim to guarantee non-discrimination in the relationships among intermediaries and different customers (conduct of business rules).
7.77 The fourth objective of financial market regulation, linked with the general objective of efficiency, is the safeguarding and promotion of competition in the financial sector. This requires rules for controlling market power and structures and, at the micro level, regulations concerning mergers and acquisitions, cartels, and abuses of dominant position. Specific controls over financial intermediaries and markets may also be justified by the attempt to limit possible destabilizing excesses generated by tough competition in such an important sector.
(p. 188) 7.78 In order to pursue these four objectives, there is neither a unique theoretical model nor just one practical approach to the regulation and supervision of financial markets. Pros and cons have been extensively discussed by many studies and significant differences are found in the literature in terms of both definition and classification of regulatory models and techniques.24 And it is difficult to observe in reality the adoption of regulatory schemes that are fully consistent with one theoretical model.
7.79 A look at the state of financial market regulatory and supervisory arrangements in the EU (including the recent and announced reforms in Ireland, the United Kingdom, Belgium, and France) show that it is still complex and not homogeneous across Member States but with a unique result: financial supervision by subject (banking, securities, and insurance/pension funds) is not chosen by any Member State even if is the choice of European regulation. Many Member States are moving from a single regulator (different from the central bank) model to a twin peaks (with prudential regulation in or out of the central bank and a separate investor protection authority) or similar model (see Table 7.1).
7.80 Nevertheless, Regulation with an ‘institutional approach’ (also known as ‘sectional’ or ‘by subjects’ or ‘by markets’) is the solution chosen by the European Authorities.
Table 7.1 Structure of financial supervision in selected countries, February 2012
Country |
Banking |
Securities |
Insurance/Pension fund |
Austria |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
Belgium |
CB/FSA |
CB/FSA |
CB/FSA |
Denmark |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
Finland |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
France |
PA/IP |
PA/IP |
PA/IP |
Germany |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
Greece |
CB |
S |
CB/G |
Ireland |
CB |
CB |
CB/PF |
Italy |
CB/S |
S/CB |
I/PF |
Luxembourg |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA/I |
Netherlands |
CB/S |
CB/S |
CB/S |
Portugal |
CB/S |
S/CB |
I |
Spain |
CB/S |
S/CB |
G |
Sweden |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
United Kingdom (end 2012) |
CB/IP |
CB/IP |
CB/IP/FP |
EU |
EBA |
ESMA |
EIOPA |
United States |
B/CB |
B/CB/S/S |
I |
Japan |
FSA |
FSA |
FSA |
Key: CB (central bank), PA (prudential authority on banks, securities, and insurance, different from CB), B (prudential agency for banks), IP (investor protection authority for banks, securities, and insurance), S (securities authority), I (insurance authority), PF (pension fund authority), FSA (single prudential and investor protection regulator), G (government department).
(p. 189) 7.81 It is true that the definition of the term ‘financial market’ has traditionally included the banking, financial, and insurance segments but the nature of financial intermediation has evolved in the last 30 years and a series of economic and legal developments has significantly changed the financial markets’ morphology.25 Today, the barriers between banking, insurance, and securities market activities have fallen together with geographic and legal restrictions, and the model of the universal bank has not only spread worldwide, but increasingly has evolved into complex financial conglomerates operating worldwide. As regards the markets, considerable integration has taken place between the banking/insurance markets and the securities markets. In most countries, banks and insurance companies are among the most important issuers of stocks and other securities traded in both organized exchanges and over the counter. Financial products and instruments have also experienced a certain degree of integration, sometimes changing their original economic function. In general, financial products have become increasingly complex, calling for new and enhanced skills in regulatory and supervisory activities.
7.82 In the more traditional ‘institutional approach’, supervision is performed over each single category of financial operator (or over each single segment of the financial market) and is assigned to a distinct agency for the entire complex of activities. In this regulatory model, which follows the traditional segmentation of the financial system into three markets, we thus have three supervisory authorities acting as watchdogs over, respectively, banks, financial intermediaries and mutual funds, and insurance companies (and the corresponding markets): the ESAs’ competences are divided similarly.
7.83 ‘Institutional’ regulation facilitates the effective realization of controls, being performed with regards to subjects that are regulated as to every aspect of their activity and as to all the objectives of regulation. Each intermediary and market has only one supervisory authority as a counterpart. The latter, in turn, is highly specialized. As a result, duplication of controls is avoided and the costs of regulation can be considerably reduced. But the institutional model could be considered optimal only in a context with rigidly separated financial segments, and where no global players are at stake.
7.84 The institutional model may give rise, in the presence of more subjects entitled to perform the same financial intermediation activities, to distortions in the supervisory activity caused by the enforcement of different dispositions for operations of the same nature that are executed by different entities.
7.85 The disadvantages of this approach are represented by the previously mentioned trend towards multiple-sector activities and by the progressive de-specialization of the intermediaries. In turn, these phenomena are connected to the growing integration of both markets and instruments, that frequently leads to the building (p. 190) of large financial conglomerates. In a context where the boundaries separating the various institutions are progressively being erased, it is no longer possible to establish whether a particular subject is a bank, a non-banking intermediary, or an insurance company; or whether a group is involved more in one or another of such activities.
7.86 Therefore, there is the risk that ‘shadow’ systems of intermediaries may be created, reflecting the diversity of the respective control authorities. In this case, the way the controls are set up may become a destabilizing rather than stabilizing factor. Moreover, the intermediaries might be induced to choose their juridical status in a way which is contingent on the different rules that discipline different subjects.
7.87 At the opposite end lies the single regulator approach which can be divided in two subclasses: the single regulator in the Central Bank (the Irish Model) or the single regulator out of the Central Bank (the former UK FSA model). A possible element of weakness in the model lies in the fact that when a single authority supervises a category of subjects and pursues more than one objective, the result of the control activity might not be effective in the event that different objectives are in conflict.
7.88 We think that a more appropriate solution is to repropose the four-peaks model of Di Giorgio, Di Noia, and Piatti (2001) adapted with some small changes. An outline of this ‘four-peaks’ model for financial regulation is provided in Figure 7.1.
7.89 Even the de Larosière Report seems to agree that the solution with EBA, ESMA, and EIOPA is cumbersome. The regulatory framework should evolve ‘towards a
(p. 191) system which would rely on only two Authorities’. The first would be responsible for banking and insurance issues, as well as any other issue which is relevant for financial stability (eg systemically important hedge funds, systemically important financial infrastructures). The second Authority would be responsible for conduct of business and market issues, across the three main financial sectors. Combining banking and insurance supervisory issues in the same Authority could result in more effective supervision of financial conglomerates and contribute to a simplification of the current extremely complex institutional landscape’ (point 216, p 58).
7.90 The three Regulations establishing the ESAs go in the same direction. Article 81 requests the European Commission to subject the three Authorities to a general review every three years (the first one will be published by 2 January 2014). Among other things the review should also examine whether:
Source Id: law-9780199660902-chapter-7-div5-90ReferencesRegulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a European Supervisory Authority (European Banking Authority), amending Decision No 716/2009/EC and repealing Commission Decision 2009/78/EC (European Parliament) (Council of the European Union) 1093/2010/EU, [2010] OJ L331/12Ch.VIII Transitional and Financial Provisions, Art.81Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a European Supervisory Authority (European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Authority), amending Decision No 716/2009/EC and repealing Commission Decision 2009/79/EC (European Parliament) (Council of the European Union) 1094/2010/EU, [2010] OJ L331/48Ch.VIII Transitional and final provisions, Art.81Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a European Supervisory Authority (European Securities and Markets Authority), amending Decision No 716/2009/EC and repealing Commission Decision 2009/77/EC (Council of the European Union) (European Parliament) 1095/2010/EU, [2010] OJ L331/84Ch.VIII Transitional and Final Provisions, Art.81
7.91 In practical terms, our proposal tends to a European System of Financial Supervision within a global framework, with the international global coordination of central banks on systemic risk and macro-prudential supervision. On the global side, there would be the aegis of the FSB, which could work for guaranteeing the financial stability and the overseeing of the systemic risk. On the European side, there could be a structure by objectives which works for the regulation at the federal level and for the supervision at the national level, thanks to the assistance of coordination committees in both of these cases.
7.92 Our four-peaks model assigns macro-stability to the ESRB with the support of ECB, and the other three objectives of prudential regulation investor/consumer protection and competition to three new ESAs which would have full regulatory powers (Level 2 agencies). These central agencies should coordinate the different domestic agencies in each member country. Apart from this vertical form of coordination, cooperation would be also desirable horizontally, at both the European and national levels. This coordination, and resolution of eventual controversies, could be provided by special Commissions for the Supervision of the Financial System established respectively at the European Commission and at national Treasuries. These commissions would be the natural place for activities involving proposals and consultation concerning measures regarding financial market regulation.
(p. 192) 7.93 We think that it would be wise to transform the EU Commission Antitrust DG into a third separate and independent central agency. This agency will then coordinate and promote the harmonized activities of domestic Antitrust agencies. In each Member State, the national Antitrust agency will safeguard competition in all economic sectors.
7.94 This federal system should obviously evolve with more supervision on Union-wide entities to the central agencies. Furthermore, macro-stability should definitively be in charge of the ECB which is the only entity able to manage some monetary policy instruments: in this regard, it is possible to foresee reinforced powers of the ECB and of all the ESFS structure for euro countries only hoping that their number will increase and not decrease.